Notes on how to deal with excess savings while limiting private leverage
- Macroprudential Policy
- Jan 1, 2020
- 4 min read
Updated: Aug 16

Since the 1980s, declining labor income shares (from 65% to 56% of GDP in advanced economies) have forced households to rely on debt to maintain consumption.
By 2008, debt saturation triggered crises (e.g., U.S. mortgage defaults). Post-crisis austerity and continued debt reliance deepened secular stagnation: weak demand, low investment (<2% GDP growth in advanced economies), and rising financial fragility.
Introduction
Since the 1980s, advanced economies have experienced a persistent decline in labor's share of income, rising inequality, and an unsustainable reliance on debt to sustain consumption. This dynamic has led to underconsumption—a chronic weakness in aggregate demand that suppresses investment and growth, creating a self-reinforcing cycle of secular stagnation. This paper examines the structural causes of underconsumption, its macroeconomic consequences, and detailed policy solutions for Japan, China, the EU, and the U.S., supported by statistical evidence and APA-referenced sources.
How Declining Labor Share Fuels Excess Savings and Debt Dependency
The decline in labor’s share of GDP since the 1980s—from ~65% to 56% in advanced economies (ILO, 2021)—has reshaped savings and debt dynamics through two key mechanisms:
A. Rising Inequality → Excess Saving Desire
Top 1% Captures Income Gains:
The top 1%’s income share doubled in the U.S. (10% to 20%, 1980–2020), while the bottom 50%’s share fell (Piketty et al., 2018).
High earners save ~40% of income vs. ~5% for the bottom 90% (Saez & Zucman, 2020).
Result: Structural excess savings emerge as capital income (profits, rents) concentrates among those with low marginal consumption.
B. Debt as the "Solution" to Underconsumption
To sustain demand despite stagnant wages:
Households Borrow: Maintain consumption via mortgages/credit cards.
U.S. household debt rose from 60% to 98% of GDP (1980–2007) (FRED, 2023).
Savings Recycled as Debt: The top 1%’s excess savings flow into:
Bonds/Mortgages (lending to the bottom 90%).
Corporate Debt (firms borrow to offset weak consumer demand).
Statistical Link:Each 1% decline in labor share correlates with a 1.4% rise in household debt/GDP (BIS, 2018).
The Unsustainable Equilibrium
Group | Income Trend | Behavior | Macro Impact |
Top 1% | Rising share | Saves excess income | Savings glut → seeks yield |
Bottom 90% | Falling share | Borrows to consume | Debt/GDP rises → fragility |
Crisis Point: Debt grows faster than incomes (e.g., U.S. household debt/income hit 140% by 2007), leading to defaults (2008) or stagnation (post-2020).
C. The Debt Saturation Point
Debt-driven growth becomes unsustainable when:
Leverage constraints bind: Banks restrict lending as DTI ratios exceed 36–43% (Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation [FDIC], 2022).
Defaults rise: U.S. mortgage delinquencies hit 11% in 2009 (Federal Reserve, 2010).
Yet, policymakers responded with more debt stimulus:
Interest rates cut to 0% (2008–2023) (Bank of England [BoE], 2023).
QE suppressed long-term yields, inflating asset prices (S&P 500 P/E rose from 15x to 30x) (Standard & Poor’s, 2023).
Result: Global debt/GDP surged from 167% (2000) to 416% (2023) (Institute of International Finance [IIF], 2023).
Secular Stagnation: A Global Phenomenon
A. Japan: The Prototype of Stagnation
Debt/GDP: 440% (2023), the highest globally (International Monetary Fund [IMF], 2023).
"Zombie firms": 30% of listed firms rely on ultra-low rates (Cabinet Office of Japan, 2023).
Policy failure: BoJ’s balance sheet hit 133% of GDP, but wages stagnated (+0.2% annually since 1990).
B. China: Debt-Fueled Growth Meets Underconsumption
Household consumption: Just 38% of GDP (vs. 55% in the U.S.).
Shadow banking: Trust loans (e.g., Evergrande’s $300B liabilities) hid risks until 2021 defaults.
C. The European Union: Stagnation by Design
Austerity’s legacy: Italy’s GDP per capita is still below 2007 levels.
ECB’s limits: QE bought €4.7T in bonds, but lending to firms grew just 1.2% annually.
D. The United States: Debt-Driven Growth Hits a Wall
Household debt: $17.3T (2023), but DTI ratios at 10.3% (near 2008 peaks).
Weak capex: Non-residential investment at 12% of GDP (vs. 15% in 2000).
Policy Solutions to Break the Underconsumption Cycle
A. Redistributive Fiscal Policies
Progressive Wealth Taxes
A 2% tax on net wealth >$50M could raise $2.7T over 10 years in the U.S. (Saez & Zucman, 2020).
EU-wide wealth tax: Proposed by Piketty (2023) to fund green transition.
Higher Minimum Wages & Collective Bargaining
Germany’s Mindestlohn raised bottom-quintile incomes by 12% (2015–2023) (German Institute for Economic Research [DIW], 2023).
Sectoral bargaining (e.g., Nordic model) reduces wage inequality by 15–20% (ILO, 2022).
B. Debt Restructuring & Financial Reform
Household Debt Relief
Student loan cancellation: U.S. could boost consumption by $90B/year (Federal Reserve, 2022).
Japan’s SME debt forgiveness (2003): Wrote off ¥75T, boosting investment by 9% (Bank of Japan [BoJ], 2005).
Financial Regulation
Ban predatory lending: U.K.’s FCA capped payday loan rates at 0.8% daily (2015), reducing defaults by 50% (Financial Conduct Authority [FCA], 2016).
Break up "too big to fail" banks: U.S. Dodd-Frank’s Volcker Rule reduced speculative trading by $1T (Federal Reserve, 2019).
C. Public Investment & Industrial Policy
Green New Deal
U.S. Inflation Reduction Act: $370B for renewables could create 1.5M jobs by 2030 (Brookings, 2023).
EU’s Just Transition Fund: €17.5B to retrain workers in fossil fuel regions (European Commission, 2023).
Tech & Infrastructure
CHIPS Act: $280B for semiconductors lifted U.S. capex by 18% (Wall Street Journal [WSJ], 2023).
China’s "Common Prosperity": $1T pledged for rural healthcare/education (People’s Bank of China [PBOC], 2023).
D. Monetary Policy Reforms
Direct Helicopter Money
COVID stimulus checks: U.S. payments boosted consumption by $1.2T (2020–2021) (U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis [BEA], 2022).
Conclusion: A New Growth Model
The underconsumption trap stems from structural inequality and flawed debt dependency. Breaking it requires:
Redistribution: Wealth taxes, wage policies.
Debt relief: Household and SME restructuring.
Public investment: Green energy, tech, infrastructure.
Monetary reform: Helicopter money.
Without these measures, secular stagnation will persist—deepening inequality and financial fragility.
Comments